Search This Blog

Tuesday 27 September 2011

The emergence of ‘new’ donors in Africa is likely to increase the bargaining power and policy space of recipient countries vis-à-vis ‘traditional’ donors. Discuss with reference to debates on aid effectiveness and policy conditionality.



For many African countries, particularly those heavily dependent on aid, (where aid constitutes more than 5% of GDP), there has been for a long time no real alternative but to agree to structural adjustment reforms and conform to a particular ‘recommended’ policy package, of that of the World Bank and IMF, EC, DFID, USAID etc... To understand the motives and patterns of aid giving, we will first look briefly at the history of the aid industry, from a political economy approach. Then, in examining each of the 5 principles of the Paris Declaration on Aid Effectiveness, we will highlight some of the issues which came about with the Washington consensus’s ascendancy and persist in the era of the so-called ‘post-Washington consensus’. The country case of Mozambique shall be used to reify the discussion of theoretical and practical flaws. For each tenet of the Paris Declaration we will consider what potential there is for new donors, particularly China, to transform the position of recipient governments in Africa, to some extent giving power back in terms of bargaining power and policy space.

A BRIEF HISTORY OF AID

As far back as 1940s and 50s aid has been linked by some to imperialism, and specifically, preventing the spread of communism; after 1959 fears of ‘another Cuba’ were felt acutely in the US (Veltmeyer & Petras; 2005). The discourse of nation-building and the reformist mentality were ideologies propagated via hefty financial backing, and still today the Maastricht Treaty of 1992 saw the EU explicitly commit to using aid in order to promote democracy. The Cold War was the main reason that aid quantities increased in 1980s (Oya; 2008) because competition between the two superpowers led not only to proxy wars in the developing world, but also benefited those countries who pledged their loyalty to one or other camp with varying degrees of boldness. The collapse of the Soviet Union and apparent victory of the free market recast the US in a ‘global leadership’ role in some minds (Fang; 2004). Eastern European countries, who had never given as much aid as OECD countries, not only ceased to disburse aid, but became aid recipients, cementing the west’s power to set the agenda and putting extra strain on limited resources provided (Degnbol-Martinussen & Engberg-Pedersen; 2003). Especially after 1983’s debt crisis therefore, donors had the leverage to dictate terms and loans began to be premised on the adoption of certain pro-market policy reforms by recipient governments, which were chiefly to the benefit of donor countries (Veltmeyer & Petras; 2005). Justifications for such intrusion have included the argument that these policies and governance choices are innately ‘good’ or ‘correct’; that widespread corruption in the developing world necessitates paternalism to ensure that aid is not siphoned off; and that to achieve pro-poor growth, (the rhetorical emphasis) poverty reduction, democracy, human rights and free-markets could only arrive as a package.

Poor countries in Africa have seen large amounts of aid go towards paying off previous debts – despite seeing little gain from the money that was loaned originally due to the stringent policies attached to it. Aid levels dropped in the 1990s due to ‘aid fatigue’, and, more importantly the fact that there was no longer a competitive element to aid-giving. As part of a geopolitical strategy, aid has been given to strengthen military and political alliances, such as the USA’s funding of counter-revolutionary forces Renamo in Mozambique and the Contras in Nicaragua (Veltmeyer & Petras; 2005). Since September 11th 2001, poverty-security linkages have become a priority (Oya; 2008), and the wars in Iraq and Afghanistan, hotbeds of ‘terror’ in the ‘axis of evil’ prompted an aid influx. Developing countries can be said to have been negatively affected by the increasing globalisation of the world. Aid has been associated with damage rather than progress and seems to be undermining prospects for long-term development. Conditionalities were never imposed on the likes of South Korea or Taiwan when they received substantial financial aid, starting in 1954, and therefore they have been able to steer their own development paths successfully (Veltmeyer & Petras; 2005). Despite liberalisation leaving them vulnerable in the 1997 economic crisis, they have recovered. By contrast, many countries that have undergone structural adjustment, have had almost no room to manoeuvre even when policies imposed by donors failed, and until China’s emergence the prospects of a counter-hegemonic power base supporting alternative policies had looked unlikely.


HARMONISATION

In terms of aid delivery, recipient countries have suffered very high administrative costs due to the sheer numbers of operational donors, and projects. With neoliberalism, the rise of NGOs has added to the proliferation of organisations which drain state capacity. Among official organisations there are around 200 bilateral and multilateral organisations (IPC; 2007) and approximately 60,000 official aid transactions were recorded in 2005 (IPC; 2007). Many of the bigger self-important agencies, suck talented civil servants away from government functions (Birdsall; 2008, Oya; 2008). It would seem common sense, and much more efficient to ‘harmonise’ these numerous actors as the Paris Declaration asks. Yet Oya (2006) points out that “an ideological consensus on policies and conditionality is very dangerous” and will only enhance ‘effectiveness’ as judged by donors’ criteria of success. This is because, although there is some heterogeneity within the western donor community (the dominant Anglo-Saxon model differing from the ‘Nordic variation’) an increasingly hegemonic New Aid Agenda is, under which 4 pillars – democratisation, poverty reduction, good governance and neoliberal reform - are lauded (Oya; 2006). This cartel creates an environment in which orthodox beliefs are taken for facts and space for deviation from the norm is minimal. Importantly, many smaller donors require World Bank or IMF approval that recipient countries are on the ‘right track’ before they will commit funds (Oya; 2006). So, while certain public goods such as the Global fund to Fight AIDS, TB and Malaria (Birdsall; 2008) do require collective work, from the perspective of recipient countries, some degree of pluralism or ‘fragmentation’ can be useful. For example India chooses its donors carefully (Oya; 2008). Despite lower administrative costs, the narrowing of choice that would occur if Roger Riddell’s vision of an ‘International Development Aid Fund’ and ‘International Aid Office’, were a reality significant. This is not to say that all international bodies, and universal pronouncements (such as the Declaration of Human Rights) are oppressive – but that in the case of political economy, space for innovation needs to be retained. If a government was deemed ‘incompetent’ they would either receive no aid or accept an external implementation agency, Riddell envisions. Arguably this is merely a ransom, which could be abused dangerously if subjective issues like the ‘best’ policies are deemed to be universal, and democratic sovereignty undermined by a single authoritative body.

According to Birdsall, donors are neither competing nor collaborating but ‘colluding’ in the absence of a competitive market for aid suppliers. This is where China’s role becomes significant because it may stimulate the ‘market’ for aid provision, as in many ways it provides a contrasting donor profile. Dealing between China and Africa have been characterised by much less bureaucracy and lower transaction costs (Oya; 2008). The Forum for China-Africa Co-operation (FOCAC) within China’s government co-ordinates much aid through the state, avoiding a multiplicity of NGOs[1][1]. One of 3 state banks, EXIM saw almost 40% of its loans go to Africa in 2007 into about 300 projects with a total worth of about $23.9 billion (Oya; 2006). China’s so-called ‘coalition engagement’, incorporating both state and market has seen Beijing increase spending dramatically especially since the turn of the millennium, and while there are commercial reasons for this engagement, China nonetheless might serve as a positional ‘counterweight’ imposing as it does, no conditions on financing (Oya; 2006). We will discuss conditionalities shortly – meanwhile it is important to acknowledge the risk that China could simply be absorbed as part of even bigger cartel. A Memorandum of Understanding (MOU) between China and World Bank was signed, and a first potential collaboration may be Mozambique’s Mphanda Nkuwa dam. For Patrick Bond (2006), China are simply a essentially new exploitative player in the long tradition of ‘looting Africa’ and instead of positive South-South co-operation this might be another brand of imperialism. However, despite signing up to the Paris Declaration, it seems probable that China will continue its own practices regardless, and while not necessarily a better or worse donor, it is a clear alternative.

MANAGING FOR RESULTS

The Paris Declaration does not explicitly address issue of conditionality or donor self-interest, but in urging aid to be ‘judged by results’ it signals several intentions. One is that the quality of aid should not be dependent on its value alone – an attempt to combat the ‘spending culture’ within the aid industry. The practice of dumping for example, is thus implicitly discouraged, and geopolitical motivations for aid alliances are downplayed in favour of humanitarian, altruistic motivations. We should expect to see as much aid going to small, strategically insignificant resource-poor countries, in an ideal world, but of course ulterior motives may well be impossible to eliminate. It’s important to keep in mind that when we discuss how ‘effective’ or ‘successful’ aid has been, different people’s varying objectives will result in different evaluations (Birdsall; 2008, IPC; 2007). Castell-Branco (2008) explains that Mazambique can thus be seen either as a great success of failure, depending on party judging and the objectives they had in mind.  Usually of course, it is the aid agencies, and not poor people, who conduct evaluations, and thus DFID’s glowing report from the OECD is not as legitimising as might be assumed (Benn & Easterly; 2006). Easterly advocates bypassing governments in order to reach the poor directly and bureaucratic channels are sometimes avoided due to donors’ desire to implement ‘their’ projects easily, besides the prevailing attitude of hostile towards the state. Sustainability, however, may require government involvement (Birdsall; 2008).

A major problem is the difficulty of measuring poverty (and reduction), for which proxies such as economic growth are often employed instead (Hudson; 2004). This practice inevitably leads back to a focus on macro-economics. Easterly accuses DFID of having too many broad and vague aims, claiming that ‘if you are responsible for everything, you are responsible for nothing’ (Benn & Easterly; 2006) and indeed a lack of specialisation is a severe problem. ‘Managing for results’ as a mantra may also discourage long-termism among donors, as tangible successes are politically preferable. Birdsall cites Impatience as one of seven ‘deadly sins’, and it is one which China has not been guilty of, with proven long term funding infrastructure, construction, even slow maturing and much needed agricultural investments which the market based model neglected. Birdsall seems to contradict herself by declaring that reluctance to exit when aid is ‘not working’ is equally as bad as ‘impatience’. This contradiction and confusion is latent in the Paris Declaration itself which seems to ignore the multiple results which projects produce. For China, managing for results means not only opening up markets for their products and tapping sources of energy, but also visible set-pieces which make a political statement.

MUTUAL ACCOUNTABILITY

The two related strands which donors hold ‘partners’ accountable for relate to ‘good policies’ being implemented (or not – ‘slippage’) and ‘good governance’ which encompasses, transparency, anti-corruption and more. The lack of trust between donors and recipients manifests itself in an ‘obsession’ with corruption. Benn believes that forcing institutional reform is acceptable because it is ‘not enough to focus on symptoms alone’, (Benn & Easterly; 2006) thereby implying that governance issues are the cause of long-standing poverty (open to debate). He names the Kenyan government as “too risky” to channel funds through, instead describing a system operating completely separately with an independent bank account which provides aid to the education sector. There is seen to be a dilemma of whether to work outside governments and risk undermining democracy or work through government and encourage corruption – so the latter option is accompanied by specific conditions. It must be noted however, that transparency is hardly an area in which donors themselves excel. Indeed, James Putzel (1998) has documented the paucity of information that is provided by the European Commission on its activities. This makes it almost impossible for the EC to be held accountable by European taxpayers, let alone recipient countries. He stresses that although multilateral aid agencies may avoid the issue of national self-interest to some degree[2][2], their supra-national status exacerbates the problem of accountability because ‘territorial boundaries of systems of accountability’ are structured around the nation-state. So on the one hand he believes, with David Held, that re-formulating the regulations governing international organisation is an urgent task, and on the other he proposes simple, cheap ways to increase accountability. Presently there are “no public guidelines outlining the criteria upon which it judges who is and who is not eligible to receive its funds” (Putzel; 1998) and nor are intended projects publicised widely enough (IPC; 2007). Lack of information not only limits participation (civil society groups must wait to be consulted) but leaves space for potentially abusive business practices. The closed market for consultantcy contracts also leads to inefficient outcomes - the system works in favour of large established forms and thus against public interest. The barriers to recipient country firms winning contracts were lessened by 1992 regulation that allowed discretion to EC in choosing whether or not to offer the opportunity to all bidders. Essentially, this is tied aid, and represents “an implicit subsidy by donor governments to donor country companies”(Oya; 2008).

Mechanisms for holding donors accountable for volatility, and unpredictability, or pro-cyclical aid giving are weak. When evaluations are made, conclusions which “challenge conventional wisdom or raise awkward questions” are rarely taken on board (Birdsall; 2008) and wholly independent assessments are badly needed. Evaluations of EC projects are almost entirely conducted from within the EC itself, not necessarily insulated from pressure, and results seldom made publicly available thus compromising their purpose (Putzel; 1998). The aid nexus in which constituents in recipient countries are affected by the operations of donor powers from the western world is an almost entirely non-democratic space. No sanctions are imposed on agencies when promises made are broken (IPC; 2007, Benn & Easterly; 2006).). Hilary Benn, formerly head of DFID, seems content with these broken promises at least signalling movement ‘in the right direction’ but this is not good enough. His talk of ‘shared responsibility’ and the ubiquitous euphemism ‘development partners’ portrays an equal relationship where in fact a clear power imbalance exists There has been a bias for ‘liberal democratic regimes’ because of the perception that aid works more effectively in such an environment (Hudson; 2004), and there has also been at attempt to make ‘poverty efficient allocation’ – demanding ‘good policies’ - take precedent over the simple principle of those who need aid most. Mozambique’s annual Programme Aid Partners’ Performance Assessment Framework (PAP’s PAF) was agreed in a 2004 MOU but it is narrowly focused in aid administration so “does not point in the direction of increasing policy space” (De Renzio & Hanlon; 2007). Instead a ‘pathological equilibrium’ exists, which entails a tolerance of corruption by donors, provided neoliberal reforms are executed, showing that accountability has been inconsistent. What might China’s presence alter? Its grants, interest free loans and concessional loans are considered non-transparent. Western donors’ professed principles can clearly be stretched, perhaps because, just as Putzel identified perverse incentives of private consultants, it is in the interests of development professionals to appear to ‘succeed’ in pet-cases like Mozambique. China makes no attempt to hide its commercial motivations and clearly prioritises resource-rich countries, tying aid to the use of Chinese firms and importing Chinese labour forces (IPC; 2007). However, the competitively priced firms are arguably still preferable to the high numbers of technocrats hired from the west. While China cannot be held particularly accountable, it does not demand accountability either – so while it can lead to support for dictators, it does not impose conditions or constraints on any government. In general there is a lack of domestic pressure on the Mozambican government, which cannot be combated by artificially creating civil society groups. If, at present the government is more accountable to donors than citizens, an indirect bonus of China’s presence may be that civil society, perceiving their government to have made a choice between Chinese and traditional donors, will more actively hold ministers to account for results (Castel-Branco; 2008).

ALIGNMENT

In theory alignment means that donors align their support to recipients’ priorities, but in practice it seems that the opposite occurs. ‘Alignment action plans’ would not be necessary if donors did not have a preconceived agenda attached to their aid giving. The process of alignment takes the form of a compromise in which recipient countries actually do most of the adjustment (Oya; 2008). The constructed rules governing aid, like trade via the WTO, are established by the global powers and will naturally reflect their interests and beliefs therefore. By a process of soft indoctrination, developing countries’ future leaders are given grants for learning and training and their education, often in the developed world, often consists of the blueprint ‘augmented Washington consensus, taught as if the gospel (Castel-Branco; 2008). The African technocrats who internalise these principles or at least appear to conform by self-censoring, will receive positive judgement from the World Bank officials. In the case of Mozambique when a PARPA was produced with striking similarity to the PRSP, praise was lavished for the high quality of the report (Castel-Branco; 2008). Hilary Benn reveals, by declaring his relief that the World Bank is moving away from the ‘wrong kind’ of conditionality, his belief that there is a ‘right kind’ (Benn & Easterly 2006). He seems to have an ‘alignment-within-reason’ attitude, stating that if three principles are adhered to, a government deserves aid – yet he shows no awareness that the universal rectitude of these principles might be questionable. Unfortunately, despite the talk of partnership, there is a strong vein of paternalism in his language, and the assumption that Britain can advise on the ‘best policies’ comes from a mentality which casually states, as he does “that’s how we did it”. The belief that poor countries must follow same path as rich countries implies that we are therefore more advanced and qualified to ‘lead the way’ and is endorsed by the very language of the ‘development community’ when is speaks of ‘developed’ and ‘developing’ countries (Veltmeyer & Petras; 2005). Besides, the economic policies pushed on developing countries are very far from policies Britain practice in its period of industrial leadership.

Has China made more genuine alignment attempts? Its engagement may be due to an interaction between aid and commercial incentives and Bond (2006) accuses China of investing primarily in ‘prestige projects’ and ‘white elephants’ such as stadiums of little benefit to ordinary people (Bond; 2006). But it has delivered much needed funds for important projects as well. Multi-country physical infrastructure projects have sometimes gone under-funded because of the system of single country loans – but China built the TAZARA railway linking Tanzania & Zambia (Oya; 2006). Ethiopia’s Takazee Dam will increase its power generating capacity considerably and even if it also benefits China’s energy needs, is thus long-term incontrovertibly a positive development. In some respects though, China seems to be pursuing its own interests above those of recipient countries, for instance in the creation of several special economic zones, the first of which, in Zambia’s Chambishi copper belt appears to be extracting minerals for China’s manufacturing industries first, and ‘aiding’ the country second, since Bond (2006) has highlighted the high environmental costs of extractive industries (PB). Chinese National Petroleum Corporation (CNPC) and two other large Chinese oil firms are active in 17 African countries and China’s growing energy needs clearly motivate this. The China Africa ‘Development’ Fund mat essentially be intended to finance market entry of Chinese firms into African economy, more than it is intent on alleviating the poor. Ultimately therefore, we should be aware that from the point of view of African governments it may be useful to have China as a threat and rival to the west’s dominance, and a business partner, primarily on order to gain more strength relative to these traditional donors, whose financial backing is still much greater.

OWNERSHIP

The concept of ownership has been exploded by Castell-Brancos (2008) in that he demonstrates it can mean anything from truly generating policies without external interference to merely exercising leadership on implementing policies. The very idea of ‘good’ and ‘bad’ on fiscal, monetary and trade issues is open to question since if some policies were indisputably good countries would not need persuasion to adopt them. The notion has been used to penalise some countries unfairly (Hudson; 2004). We could similarly interrogate the idea of ‘good governance’ which self defines as superior but is a normative question. Low budget deficit, high trade openness and low inflation are usually demanded by neo-classical economics, but have failed to deliver growth to Africa. Investment depressing conditions have been created by high interest rates in many countries (IPC; 2007) and the IMF’s fear of pushing up the exchange rate, the ‘Dutch disease’ has meant that spending has been severely constrained (IPC; 2007). Forced liberalisation (along with unpredictability of aid) necessitated reserve accumulation (Lapavitsas; 2007) and  in the case of Mozambique’s cashew industry held disastrous consequences for the country but no consequences for World Bank. Easterly implies that the idea of ownership is merely a ‘dysfunctional contradictions’ and ‘evasion of responsibility’, a way of shifting the blame on to developing country governments when policies back-fire. Badly designed deflationary policies geared at repaying debts from the 1980s caused recession in several countries, but the Washington-consensus, even in augmented form, has changed little. It should be remembered that the IMF doesn’t have the sectoral expertise to involve itself everywhere, and macro-economic choice pertain to “fundamental social choices that should be left to national political processes” (IPC; 2007). But the rather than questioning its own foundations, the World Bank’s CPIA is used to assess the quality of a country’s policies.

The fact that donors twice withheld food aid from Mozambique – in 1983 and 1986 – to force the country to join the Bretton Woods institutions and to pressure it to agree to structural adjustment respectively is pertinent. There were disastrous consequences for many hungry Mozambicans (De Renzio & Hanlon; 2007). So although subservience is a choice in itself, Mozambique’s history and the lack of donors content to be only donors and not policy-makers meant the country complied with donor demands and has been seen as a success, growing at an average of 8%. Castell-Branco’s very nuanced Gramscian analysis of power relations between Mozambique and its donors includes the point that it has not simply been a story of domination from one side and subordination despite resistance on the other. Indeed, there are two clear examples of defiance, the first on land privatisation where agrarian populism among the people contributed vitally to the government resisting the World Bank’s pressure. The second has been a more passive resistance to anti-corruption measures, but crucially, donors have been tolerant and pragmatic. At the same time, President Guebeza’s desire to create a development bank to give rural has been refused by donors. But, public protests in 1990s by progressive bilateral donors against the IMF’s unpopular policies restricting social spending and capping spending on civil service salaries saw an easing of these measures – and instance of positive fragmentation. Such fluid power play leads to an overall “loss of policy coherence” (Oya; 2006) and prevents the emergence of a developmental state with a long-term strategic vision. If it is true that “the only developing countries that did well in the [globalisation] context, were those that ignored the policy prescriptions of the WB and the IMF” (Veltmeyer & Petras; 2005), why did African countries acquiesce? Had China been as powerful twenty years ago, and its historic support for the liberation-movement cum governing party FRELIMO was of more value, this might have precipitated a split in the party. In reality the faction of the party which was against neoliberal reform simply became marginalised but were relatively powerless to prevent the new order and saw no reason to break away due to lack of potential support. Perhaps a contest might have ensued and China’s experience could have provided valuable concrete lessons, rather than beng the source of a complete ‘alternative model’. China’s own development has for a long time been non-ideological, and its economy mixed. The policy of non-interference and such drivers of growth as the State Owned Enterprises, show China to be a very different success story to that of Anglo-American capitalism. China has liberalised trade only slowly and partially, on its own terms, and like other East Asian countries have retained subsidies, licenses, price control mechanisms in industrial policy. Under the aegis of the IFIs, developing countries have had little true ownership, but China’s arrival on the scene may provide more room for assertion of sovereignty.

CONCLUSION – IFS AND BUTS

Donors are keen for success. Despite the Paris Declaration, official policies have not penetrated well at country level, and tangible development results are still placed before these principles by a plethora of contradictory incentive structures (IPC; 2007). Even the move towards General Budget Support can be seen as introducing donors closer to the heart of government, rather than empowering recipient governments. We shouldn’t over-estimate China’s wealth – its official aid target for 2009 was $1billion compared to the OECD’s annual figure of around $30billion. (Oya; 2008). China’s indirect and symbolic use may well be its greatest asset for African countries at present. In the long-term however, China’s growth and increasing engagement with Africa and the rest of the world, might herald a possible global alternative to neoliberal capitalism help developing countries to escape the narrow policies which have held back growth and kept them reliant on aid.
Bibliography

Benn H. and W. Easterly (2006). 'Is Aid Working?' Debate between Hillary Benn (former Head of DFID) and W. Easterly in Prospect magazine, Issue 128, December.

Birdsall N. (2008). 'Seven Deadly Sins: Reflections on Donor Failings'. In Easterly (ed.) Reinventing Foreign Aid, chapter 20. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

Bond, P. (2006). Looting Africa. London: Zed Books, chapter 4.

Castel-Branco C (2008). 'Aid Dependency and Development: a Question of Ownership? A Critical View' IESE Working Paper n. 1/2008, Maputo, Mozambique.

Degnbol-Martinussen J. and P. Engberg-Pedersen (2003) Aid: Understanding International Development Cooperation. London: Zed Books. Chapter 2 and 12.

De Renzio, P. and J. Hanlon (2007). Contested Sovereignty in Mozambique: The Dilemmas of Development. Global Economic Governance Programme Working Paper 2007/25.

Fang, T. (2004). ‘Review of Nolan China at the Crossroads’ The Copenhagen Journal of Asian Studies, n. 19; 105-111

Hudson J. (2004) 'Introduction: Aid and Development' Economic Journal 114, June 185-190. Special Issue on Aid and Development.

International Poverty Centre (2007). 'Does Aid Work? - for the MDGs', Poverty in Focus, pp. 1-28, October. This is a summary of results of recent influential publications on aid.

Lapavitsas C. (2007). 'Using ODA to Accumulate Foreign Reserves in Sub-Saharan Africa'. International Poverty Centre One Pager n. 37.

Oya, C. (2006). 'The political economy of development aid as main source of foreign finance for African countries: loss of policy space and possible alternatives from East Asia' Paper presented at the Second Annual Conference of the International Forum on the Comparative Political Economy of Globalization conference, 1-3 September 2006, Renmin University of China, Beijing, China.

Oya C. (2008). 'Greater Africa-China Economic Cooperation: Will This Widen 'Policy Space'?', Development Viewpoint n. 4, Centre for Development Policy and Research, SOAS, London.

Putzel, J., (1998) 'The Business of Aid: Transparency and Accountability in European Union Development Assistance', Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 34, No. 3, (February)

Veltmeyer H. and James Petras (2005) 'Foreign Aid, Neoliberalism and US Imperialism' chapter 13 in Saad-Filho and D. Johnston (eds.) Neoliberalism: A Critical Reader, pp. 120-126.


[1][1] Though it could be argued that NGOs are more likely than states to have humanitarian and no other motivation for their work, it could equally be said that NGOs sometimes unwitting serve geopolitical interests unconsciously (NL).
[2][2] But in this case he identifies Asia as a deliberate target area for the EU and believes aid policy there to be part of a broader strategic plan for the Union’s external relations.

Thursday 22 September 2011

Wednesday 1 June 2011

A retrospective essay on the implications on criminalising migrants and mobility in MENA region. A casestudy of Libya-Italy relation pre-civil war.

 What are the implications of certain forms of migration and mobility being criminalised in the context of the Middle East and North Africa 
Introduction.
The European Union’s Schengen Agreement[1] on open borders has externalised its border controls to the Middle East and North Africa. Italy has, with perseverance, pursued hard-line bilateral agreements with Libya, implementing heavily armed border guards to patrol its waters. In doing so, certain Italian political parties such as the Lega del Nord[2] (Northern League) have coerced the general public into believing that irregular migrants arriving from the MENA region are criminals.  One implication of this apparent criminalisation has been to enable Italy to ‘repatriate’ migrants to Libya without the ability to claim asylum protection. Many migrants, once returned to Libya, suffer intense human right abuses as Libya begins to adopt the E.Us far-right rhetoric against immigration.  Furthermore, with the tightening of European border controls human smuggling and trafficking industries have been left as one of the few viable routes into Europe. In turn, this has tended migration as a whole to be seen as a criminal activity.
The first section of this paper will introduce a synopsis of the migration patterns, routes and historical background in migratory relations between the Middle East North Africa (MENA) and Southern Europe. The second part will examine and clarify the different interpretations between aspects of irregular migration. A distinction between human trafficking and human smuggling will be produced discussing how the international community has approached these diverse yet inter-related practices. To provide a case-study the third part of the essay will offer an examination into how Italian has politically criminalised irregular migrants and what effect these policies have had on the media and the general public. The fourth section will investigate how Italy (and European) policies and attitudes towards irregular migration have led to an increase in human trafficking and smuggling and human rights abuse in Libya. The paper will conclude by examining how due to the E.U’s and Italy’s restrictive border controls, migrants and the practice of migration, has come to be conceived as a criminal act.
History & Routes.
The end of World War II, and the rise of European labour immigration from the Middle East and North Africa (MENA) in the 1960s, along with the economic expansion and subsequent oil-crisis in the Gulf Cooperation Council countries[3], migration established as a continuous contemporary phenomenon in the MENA. However, the foundations of present MENA immigration to Italy were set in stone soon after the independence of transit countries[4] such as Algeria, Morocco and Libya.
Following the UN’s 1992-2000 embargo, Libya pursued ‘pan-African’ policies. These strategies not only welcomed large numbers of labour migrants but also allowed Libya to strengthen political ties with many neighbouring African countries. During the 1980’s many migrants from West Africa and Central Africa fled to Libya escaping drought, civil war and growing wide spread political instabilities. During the 1990’s Libya, with these new ‘pan-African’ immigration policies, witnessed an intensification of regular and irregular migration. By 1995, according to Bredeloup & Pliez (2006) 90% of Libya’s sub-Saharan population originated from Sudan, Chad and Niger.
As Libya’s population rapidly grew, Italy, which prior to 1991 had relatively lax immigration laws with small penalties for irregular immigrants, soon became a destination for MENA originating migrants. The popularity of Italy was “not only due to its exposed geographical location, but also the needs of the economy and the governmental policy. Labour-intensive underground industries rely extensively on immigrant labour, whose wages are very low by European standard” (Vayrynen,2003:14). This permitted Italy to sustain its large informal sector with cheap labour, allowing the black market to grow in 1998 to 28.0% of its gross domestic product (GDP)[5] (Bovi,2002:20)[6], [Figures 2].
Post 1991 Italy introduced visa requirements for Maghrebi migrants ending free seasonal and circular migration from the MENA. Subsequently, Libya not only intensified as migratory destination in its own right[7] but also became fertile ground for smuggling and trafficking industries to establish. By 2004 up to 80% of irregular migrants to the E.U, following the ‘North African Route’ departed from the Libyan ports of Zuwarah and Zilten, disembarking on the Sicilian island of Lampedusa (Baldwin-Edwards,2005:18), (Sorensen, 2006:55). In 2006, Zuwarah acted as the main point of departure for smuggling networks operating in Libya [Figure 1+2]. Libya is now considered the main transit country in North Africa with its authorities estimating “that currently [2006] the foreign population residing in Libya is 600,000, and that a further 750,000 to 1.2 million are residing illegally” (Sorensen, 2006:27).
Map 1: Transit Migration Routes from Africa (MENA) to Europe.
 (ICMPD,2004 – sourced: Baldwin-Edwards,2005:18)
Map 2: Irregular Migration Routes from Libya to Italy.
(Sorensen, 2006:55)
Definitions of Irregular Migration
This essay, while focusing on irregular migration, will not artificially dissociate the process of human smuggling from that of human trafficking, primarily because as the second section will explore, both practices are known to be reciprocally interrelated. It is essential to note the subtle differences between smuggling and trafficking, to what extent their interactions have affected the international community’s response in categorising the two processes, and how their relationship plays a key role in the criminalising of migrants both in the political and societal sphere.
The criminal and/or exploitative acts associated to smuggling and trafficking are generally considered interchangeable, whilst the manner in which the two processes unravel can be distinctly different. “Human trafficking is considered the transportation of people from one place to another for exploitative purposes through coercion, deception, or some other form of illicit influence, while human smuggling is associated more with illegal border crossing under the assistance of third parties”(Icduygu & Toktas, 2002:28). Smuggling implies a voluntarily purchase of illegal services to evade international border controls. Arab states play various and multiple roles on migration routes. They act both as destination, transit and recruitment points for the traffickers, smugglers and smuggled or trafficked individuals. (Arab Human Development Report, 2009: 8).
Trafficking and smuggling challenge traditional migration theories. “They blur the boundaries between forced and voluntary movements and between legality and illegality” (Salt,2000:35). Consequently human trafficking and human smuggling, although possessing separate UN Protocols[8] are considered to be part of the UN Convention on Trans-national Organized Crime (UN,2004:41,53). Primarily this is associated with the fact that unlike many other migratory patterns trafficking and smuggling are covert activities.
Data collection on both activities has predominantly been sporadic rather than systematic. “From a methodological standpoint, one of the most persistently difficult problems in this field is the measurement and analysis of determinants of unauthorized immigration. The illegal flow of persons across national borders wreaks havoc with national population statistics”(Portes & DeWind 2007:11-13).
States have therefore developed diverse definitions for smuggling and trafficking. Effectively, different interpretations play a key role in data collection methods and policy implementations. Hence the implications of whom is a victim or perpetrator has become a major factor[9]. The practice of criminalising human smuggling in comparison to human trafficking, is a “process leading a person or group of people to be the object, first, of repressive action by the police forces, an then to undergo judicial proceedings”(Palidda,2009:11). Human trafficking on the other hand, is criminalised as a process of irregular migration, defined as “crossing borders without proper authority, or violating conditions for entering another country” (Jordan&Duvell,2002:15).
Although smuggling and trafficking share common aspect of being irregular migratory paths, they are diverse patterns of migration. States have repeatedly coupled the two processes whilst predominantly disregarding their differentiation. In portraying smuggling and trafficking as the same process, public opinion of irregular migration as whole is misinterpreted. The role played by language in creating power relations and social and political identities is key in understanding the process by which migrants have been criminalised[10]. The common portrayal of irregular migrants as desperate and impoverished has led to distorted media images and exaggerated policy discourses overstating the magnitude of irregular migration from Africa (de Haas, 2008:49).
Italy’s Political Criminalisation of Migrants.
Drawing on Europe’s (specifically Italy’s) migration policies post-fall of the Berlin Wall (November 1989) we note that Europe has become increasingly more determined to restrict migrants originating from the MENA. European migration policies changed towards accepting labour migrants from the Eastern Europe rather than from the MENA.
“It was from the start of the 1990s that European police forces ended up adopting racial profiling as an instrument of customary repression and control and the selection of immigrants, informal but nonetheless effective, was primed to favour people coming from eastern countries…In countries of long-standing immigration, criminalisation increasingly took on racist features” (Palidda,2009:11).
The second report by the European Commission Against Racism and Intolerance, heavily criticised Italy’s “diffuse employment of racist and xenophobic propaganda from certain exponents of Italian political parties. Such propaganda is focused on non-EU migrants and on those that lack legal status” (ECRI,2002:25-sourced Paoletti,2009:10). The report argued that Italian political debates were responsible for associating migration with drug trafficking and prostitution, further marginalising and criminalising MENA migrants.
Disembarkation of migrants on the island Lampedusa enabled Italian politicians to describe it as an “assault” or an “invasion”[11].  Analogies of migration bordering on the edge of legality have been reoccurring themes of the recent Italian politics, with Berlusconi stating in 2010:
“Una riduzione degli extracomunitari significa meno forze che vanno ad ingrossare le schiere delle criminalità”[12] (Repubblica,29 gennaio 2010).
Furthermore Roberto Maroni, a leading member of the Lega del Nord (Northern League) and minister of Labour and Welfare during Berlusconi’s second and third governments from 2001 until May 2006, stated:
 “Il mio compito…è sostenere una linea molto vigorosa sulla sicurezza, tenendo conto anche dei contributi critici che stanno arrivando in questi giorni. Il principio è garantire la massima sicurezza ai cittadini, prevenire e combattere in modo rigoroso l'immigrazione clandestina e affermare il principio di legalità”[13]  (Ministro dell’interno, 2008)  
These political statements criminalising migrants depict not only negative connotations but are also hard to sustain when it is observed that “from 1990 to 2009, the total number of crimes has decreased, while immigrants (both regular and irregular) have increased by 420%”(Palidda,2009:174). [Figure 3].
Figure 3:Registered crimes 1990-2008
(Palidda,2009:174)
The Implications Amplified by the Media.
The catalyzing of the ‘assault’ of migrants on Italian shores is further articulated when it is noted that Italy, unlike many other European countries, is ‘privileged’ with a particularly tight relationship between state and media[14]. “Italy’s heady blend of politics and media has made headlines inside and outside the country, with watchdogs…pointing to Prime Minister Berlusconi's influence over both public and private broadcasting…Italy's TV market…are a potentially powerful political tool” (http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/world/europe/country_profiles/1065345.stm#media).
Italian media outlets are heavily drawn to populist tones, discussing immigration in a ”thematic spectrum that fits into the frames of invasion (arrivals in boats, overcrowding of detention centres, expulsion orders), of Islamic terrorism…and, with a typically Italian doggedness, into that of security (a more suggestive way of calling the obsession for the criminal activity of immigrants, that may include anything, regardless of whether it involves criminal offences or not: from violence to dealing, from murder to prostitution, from cowboy drivers to sellers of counterfeit goods) (Maneri,2009:29). It is therefore unsurprising that generally a crime reporter discusses immigration issues, swaying the overall public to consider “migration as a social threat” (Paoletti,2009:9).
The correlation between xenophobia, media and the evolution of criminalising migrants has not only been particular to Italy, but also to Europe as a whole. In 2006 the Report on Racism and Xenophobia presented by the Fundamental Rights Agency to the Civil Liberties Committee claimed that racism still remained “a serious social ill across Europe” European Union Agency for Fundamental Rights, 2007).
Human Rights Implications
If we pass from the political and media dialogue that has led to a criminalisation of immigrants to considering the effects, we note that the European response has been to “send them back” (Baldwin-Edwards, 312:2006). Italy (like many other E.U. states) seems to ignore, that as IOM (International Organisation for Migration) spokesman Flavio Di Giacomo expressed, “if all migrants just stopped working now, the Italian economic system would collapse”(Itano,20:2010).
Nevertheless, Italy has independently pursued bilateral agreements with Libya, whereby migrants are instantly deported (‘repatriation flights’) when caught by the authorities, disregarding their human and asylum rights. “In October 2004 Italy returned 1,000 people, without allowing them to claim asylum, to Libya…this meant that effectively the migrants were denied the right to asylum even though they had arrived in an EU country[15](Baldwin-Edwards, 320:2006). Furthermore, in July 2009 the Italian government amended the 1998 Unified Text on Immigration. The revision of Article 6 introduced a one-year imprisonment and a fine of up to 2,000 Euros to an irregular in Italy (Parlamento Italiano2009:4). 
The expulsion of migrants to transit countries such as Libya has led the Italian government to “be criticized by, among other organizations, the European Parliament, the European Committee for the Prevention of Torture, Amnesty International, Human Rights Watch and the UNHCR” (Paoletti,2009:16).
‘Repatriation flights’ potentially entail grave human right abuses, especially when considering that Libya does not recognise the Geneva Convention (view footnote 15), nor the OAU asylum procedures[16]. Many migrants suffer detention for indefinite periods as well as sometimes being submitted to forms of slavery[17]. It has also been observed, with growing evidence, that Libya after receiving the ‘collective repatriations’ by the Italian authorities deport (along with other migrants it has apprehended) and abandon them in the middle of the desert[18], leaving few able to survive[19] (Vassallo Paleologo, 2009:232), (Baldwin-Edwards 2006), (Del Grande, 2007).
In December 2007, Italy and Libya signed an agreement on the joint patrolling of coasts, ports and bays, “Italy committed itself to providing six patrol boats to Libya, and in January 2008 the Italian Parliament approved the allocation of over €6 million for the Guardia di Finanzia[20] (Paoletti, 2009:15). Italy has pursued these bilateral agreements with the conviction that they will tackle the core issues regarding the ‘invasion’ of Lampedusa, as Roberto Maroni stated in 2008:
 “potremo dire addio una volta per tutte al problema degli sbarchi a Lampedusa”.
Libya’s echo of Italy’s Policies.
Ironically, the implications of these hard-line approaches taken by Italy and Libya have been one of the fundamental reasons why migrants are engaging in illegal smuggling and trafficking. “While smuggling is commonly represented as one of the main ‘causes’ of irregular migration, it is rather the result of increasingly restrictive migration policies” (de Haas, 2008:49). In turn this has allowed for bureaucratic institutions to easily criminalise migrants and in doing so violate their human rights (Soresen, 2008:122).
The ability of Libya to manage these variant aspects of migration has now become central. Particularly when considering that Libya, apart from being a migratory destination in its own right as well as a transit country, now deals with the treatment of the irregular, returned, asylum seeking and refugee migrants that Italy has mishandled, criminalised and deported. With the E.U. externalising asylum and immigration policies to Libya through proposals, such as that of Franco Frattini’s (European Commissioner for Justice, Freedom and Security) “to move aero-naval patrols into Libyan waters from 2008 onwards” (Del Grande, 2007:3), Libya has come to express sentiments of being ‘bottle-necked’[21] with migrants, whereby they not only police their own borders but also those of Europe.
            “The Europeans want us to be their police along their borders” (Paoletti,2009:17).
Indeed, Libya has come to echo concerns on immigration similar to those of Italy. As the Libyan Foreign Minister, Rahman Shalgham stated, “If for you Italians, illegal immigration is a problem, for us it’s much more – it’s an invasion” (Paoletti,2009:6).
As the European Community has criminalised migrants and ‘collectively repatriated’ them to the MENA, the major implication has been that Libya has come to consider migration (much like Europe) as a security issue, specifically in five areas: unemployment, national identity, spread of new diseases, education standards and criminality.
Firstly, unemployment, according to the IMF “may be as high as 30 percent remain[ing] one of Libya’s greatest problems”(Vandewalle,2006:188). In relation to national identity it has been stated that,
“There are some villages in the South and in the desert that are undergoing a process of ‘Africanisation’. In these parts of the country, the African outnumber the Libyans. This clearly raises some questions concerning integration and national identity” (Paoletti,2009:8).
Thirdly, the Ministry of the Interior and the Ministry of Foreign Affairs has come to suggest that migrants are responsible for the spread of HIV and other diseases that did not previously exist in Libya. In regards to education, the rise in migration is blamed as a root cause for not achieving previous successes in education. Libya claims that due to the depletion of resource it’s been unable to uphold its high universal enrolment in primary education and the 14% illiteracy rate, which is below the regional average of 34%. (World Bank, 2006:7). Nonetheless, as Paoletti (2009:9) notes, “this information has neither been confirmed nor disproved by other sources” due to the absence of comprehensive data on education standards.
Furthermore, migration is treated as a security issue because of its alleged links to the rise in crimes and terrorism. Much like Europe, Libya in supporting the increased immigration controls for the E.U. borders has taken full advantage of the concerns about terrorism generated by 9/11[22]. For as the Paoletti report demonstrates from several interviews with Libyan Professors:
“60% or 50% of migrants are Muslim and many come from countries where there are extremist organisations”…“Migrants represent a link with the foreign community and terrorist organizations. The link has been proved” (Paoletti,2009:8).
Conclusion
Human right abuses and criminalisation acts against migrants in countries such as Libya are effectively legitimized by Italy’s far-right policies. The Italian government in implementing extreme border controls, whilst dispersing media coverage referring to migrants as social burdens, alleged or proven criminals, or even affiliates of terrorism has effectively constructed negative public perception of “clandestines”. As long as the E.U. continues to criminalise migrants and diverse migration patterns, immigration will not be recognised as “intimately connected with the transformation of the world economy” (Vayrynen,2003:1).
Fundamentally the implication of criminalising migrants is that migration itself has come to be conceived as a dangerous and criminal route out of poverty. The marginalisation of migrants promotes the undertaking of illegal migratory routes such as smuggling and trafficking, all of which further encourage and guarantee the abuse of human rights and the underdevelopment of the MENA region (Baldwin-Edwards,2006:314).
In conclusion with countries such as Libya increasingly acting as an extension of the E.U’s borders, the negative European rhetoric towards migrants and migration has grown. Leaving Libya eagerly to adopt and amplify “its concerns on immigration in way that resembles the European far right security paradigm” (Paoletti,2009:20). 

Bibliography
-Baldwin-Edwards, M. (2006) ‘”Between a rock and a hard place”: North Africa as a region of emigration, immigration and transit migration.’ Review of African Political Economy, 33, 311-324.
-Baldwin-Edwards, M. (2005) Migration in the Middle East and Mediterranean, A paper prepared for the Policy Analysis and Research Programme of the Global Commission on International Migration. Panteion University Athens, Greece.
-Bhabha, J. & Zard, M. (2006). Smuggled or Trafficked? Forced Migration Review, number 25.
-Bovi, M. (2002). The Nature of the Underground Economy. Some Evidence From OECD Countries,  ISAE Istituto di Studi e Analisi Economica. Rome
-Bredeloup, S. et Pliez, O. (2006) Migration entre les deux rives du Sahara. Migrations Societe, Vol 18; Numb 107, pages 265-266.
-de Haas .H (2008). Irregular Migration from West Africa to the European Union: An Overview of Recent Trends. IOM Migration Research Series, No. 32, Geneva. P14.
-Demir, J. S. (2003a) The trafficking of women for sexual exploitation: a gender-based and well-founded fear of persecution? Geneva: UNHCR.
-Duvell, f. (2006). Crossing the fringes of Europe: Transit migration in the EU’s neighbourhood. Centre on Migration, Policy and Society, University of Oxford, Oxford.
-Edwards, A. (2008). Traffic in Human Beings: At the Intersection of Criminal Justice, Human Rights, Asylum/Migration and Labor.
-European Union Agency for Fundamental Rights, (2007) Report on Racism and Xenophobia in the EU Member States.
-Del Grande, G. (2007) Fortress Europe, Escape from Tripoli, Report on the conditions of migrants in transit in Libya. Rome
-İcduygu, A. and Toktas, S. (2002) ‘How do smuggling and trafficking operate via irregular border crossings in the Middle East?’ International Migration, 40/6, pp. 25-54.
-Itano, N. (2010) Southern Europe’s Immigration Test. Time magazine March, 01, 2010.
-Jordan, B. and Duvell, F. (2002) Irregular Migration: The Dilemmas of Transnational Mobility, Edwards Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.
-Maneri, M. (2009) Media and the war on immigration. Criminalisation and Victimisation of Migrants in Europe, Work Package 3 Criminalisation and Decriminalisation Process, Crimprev, Assessing Deviance, Crime and Prevention in Europe, Dipartimento di Scienze Antropologiche, Unversita degli Studi di Genova.
- D. Melossi, ed., Symposium on Migration, punishment and social control in Europe, «Punishment and Society», 4/2003, 371-462 ; Palidda S., 2008, Mobilità umane. Introduzione alla sociologia delle migrazioni, Milan, Raffaelo Cortina; E. Guild, Les étrangers en Europe, victimes collatérales de la guerre contre le terrorisme, in D. Bigo, L. Bonelli, T. Deltombe, dir., Au nom du 11 septembre. Les démocraties à l’épreuve du terrorisme, Paris, La Découverte; 2008, pp. 139-150
-O.A.U, (10th September 1969), Convention Governing the Specific Aspects of Refugee Problems in Africa. Refugee Convention.
-Palidda, (2009) Introduction Criminalisation and Victimisation of Migrants in Europe, Work Package 3 Criminalisation and Decriminalisation Process, Crimprev, Assessing Deviance, Crime and Prevention in Europe, Dipartimento di Scienze Antropologiche, Unversita degli Studi di Genova.
-Paoletti, E. (2009) The Case of Italy, Libya and the EU,RAMSES Working Paper 12/09 April 2009, European Studies Centre, University of Oxford.
-Portes, A. & deWind, J (2007) “A Cross-Atlantic Dialogue: the Process of Research and Theory in the Study of International Migration.” In PORTES, A. and DE WIND, J. (Eds.) Rethinking Migration: New Theoretical and Empirical Perspectives, Oxford, New York: Berghahn Books.
-Salt, J. (2000) ‘Perspectives on the trafficking of migrants’. International Migration, 38 (3): 31-56.
-Sciortino, G. & Colombo, A., (2004), Gli Immigrati in Italia, Bologna: Il Mulino.
-Schneider ,S. (2002).  Size and Measurement of the Informal Economy in 110 Countries Around the World. Workshop of Australian National Tax Centre, ANU, Canberra, Australia.
-Segretaria Organizzativa Federale (2000), Cronistoria Della Lega Nord Dalle Origini ad Oggi, Quinta Parte 2000.
-Sorensen, N. (2006) Mediterranean Transit Migration, Danish Institute for International Stidoes, Copenhagen.
-United Nations (2000) Protocol Against the Smuggling of Migrants by Land, Sea and Air, Supplementing the United Nations Convention Against Transnationalism. General Assembly resolution 54/212 of 22 December 1999.
-United Nations (2000) Protocol to the Convention Against Transnational Organized Crime, The Trafficking Protocol to Prevent, Suppress and Punish Trafficking in Persons, especially Women and Children, United Nations, General Assembly, 11th Session, adopted by Resolution 55/25,  signed 12-15 December 2000, Palermo
-UN, (2004). United Nations Convention Against Transnational Organised Crime and the Protocols Thereto. United Nations Office of Drugs and Crime, Vienna.
-United Nations Development Programme, Regional Bureau for Arab States. Arab Human Development Report, (2009). Challenges to Human Security in the Arab Countries. New York.
- UNHCR. (1st September 2007), Convention and Protocol Relating to the Status of Refugees, UNHCR Media Relation and Public Information Service, http://www.unhcr.org/protect/PROTECTION/3b66c2aa10.pdf
-Wolrd Bank, (2006) Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya Country Economic Report, Report No. 0295-LY.
-Vandewalle, D. (2006) A History of Modern Libya,  Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
-Vassallo Paleologo, F. (2009) Lampedusa, Europe’s Guantanamo?
The practice of prohibitionism of migrations and violation of fundamental rights at the Sicilian border, (Università di Palermo), Criminalisation and Victimisation of Migrants in Europe, Work Package 3 Criminalisation and Decriminalisation Process, Crimprev, Assessing Deviance, Crime and Prevention in Europe, Dipartimento di Scienze Antropologiche, Unversita degli Studi di Genova.
-Vayrynen, R. (2003) Illegal Immigration, Human Trafficking, and Organized Crime. Discussion Paper No. 2003/72. United Nations University. WIDER World Institute for Development Economics Research.
Internet resources:
http://www.interno.it/mininterno/export/sites/default/it/sezioni/servizi/legislazione/immigrazione/legislazione_200.html
http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/foucault/
http://ricerca.repubblica.it/repubblica/archivio/repubblica/2010/01/29/berlusconi-meno-immigrati-per-sconfiggere-la-criminalita.html


[1] “The Schengen area and cooperation are founded on the Schengen Agreement of 1985. The Schengen area represents a territory where the free movement of persons is guaranteed. The signatory states to the agreement have abolished all internal borders in lieu of a single external border. Here common rules and procedures are applied with regard to visas for short stays, asylum requests and border controls. Simultaneously, to guarantee security within the Schengen area, cooperation and coordination between police services and judicial authorities have been stepped up. Schengen cooperation has been incorporated into the European Union (EU) legal framework by the Treaty of Amsterdam of 1997” (http://europa.eu/legislation_summaries/justice_freedom_security/free_movement_of_persons_asylum_immigration/l33020_en.htm).
[2] The Northern League can be compared to the British BNP and the France’s Front National. The Northern League holds 8.1% of the Italian government and 25 seats, making it the third strongest party in the country. (http://electionresources.org/it/senate.php?election=2008).
[3] The Cooperation Council for the Arab States of the Gulf (GCC) is a regional organisation consisting of six Gulf countries: Bahrain, Kuwait, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabia and United Arab Emirates. The GCC was created in May 1981. Its main objectives are to enhance coordination, integration and inter-connection among its Member States in different spheres. During the past decades the countries of the Cooperation Council of the Arab States of the Gulf (GCC) have witnessed an unprecedented economic and social transformation. Oil proceeds have been used to modernize infrastructure, create employment, and improve social indicators, while the countries have been able to accumulate official reserves, maintain relatively low external debt, and remain important donors to poor countries. All the GCC member states are members of the Arab League and Qatar, Saudi Arabia, Kuwait and the United Arab Emirates are the prominent members of OPEC. (http://ec.europa.eu/external_relations/gulf_cooperation/index_en.htm), (http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/med/2003/eng/fasano/index.htm),                                               See: http://www.gcc-sg.org/eng/index.php
[4] Transit countries are countries whereby transit migration is undertaken by people entering a national territory who may stay for a period of weeks or months whilst gathering funds and organising the next part of the migratory trip. It is the process by which a migrant will enter a country but leave following a certain amount of time to an onward destination.
See:
-Duvell, f. (2006). Crossing the fringes of Europe: Transit migration in the EU’s neighbourhood. Centre on Migration, Policy and Society, University of Oxford, Oxford.
-de Haas .H (2008). Irregular Migration from West Africa to the European Union: An Overview of Recent Trends. IOM Migration Research Series, No. 32, Geneva. P14.
[5] For more info see: Schneider ,S. (2002).  Size and Measurement of the Informal Economy in 110 Countries Around the World. Workshop of Australian National Tax Centre, ANU, Canberra, Australia
[6] More info view tables on page 20 and 21.
[7] See Bawldwin-Edwards, M. (2006) ‘”Between a rock and a hard place”: North Africa as a region of emigration, immigration and transit migration.’ Review of African Political Economy, 33, p313 for discussion on how Libya, apart from being a transit country has been a migratory destination of its own. Primarily owing to its development of oil and a high per capita GDP, with an estimated 1.1-1.4 million up to 1.8 million, of which 600,000 are legal workers, with a population recorded around 5.5m, immigration ratio to population in the order of 25-30%. With E.U border controls tightening Libya migratory role intensified.
[8] The trafficking and smuggling of human beings has been a focus for the International Community for over a century. In 2000 the Protocol to Prevent, Suppress and Punish Trafficking in Persons, Especially Women and Children (2000 TP) (UN,2000: 3, art. 3) further expanded the scope of previous International conventions on human trafficking (1904 and subsequent 1910, International Agreement for the Suppression of the White Slave Traffic, the 1949 Convention of the Suppression of Traffic in Persons and the Exploitation of the Prostitution of Others…etc) to include “a range of non-prostitution-related trafficking offences, such as trafficking for forced labor or services, slavery, servitude and removal of organs” (Edwards,2008:14). Following the 2000 TP and in recognition of the subtle logistical and legal differences, along with the prevailing conviction that “smuggled adult migrants are male, while trafficked adult migrants are female”(Demir,2003:7) the UN acknowledged that the act of human smuggling demanded a separate protocol. In the year 2000, soon after signing the 2000 TP, the 2000 Protocol against the Smuggling of Migrants by Land, Sea and Air was adopted (UN,2000,art.2, art.3,3).
[9] For as Bhabha & Zard (2006) stated, “there is much to be gained from being classified as trafficked, and much to lose from being considered smuggled” (Bhabha & Zard, 2006:7).
[10] For further discourse on an analysis of how language shows uses techniques and institutions, developed for different and often quite innocuous purposes, converged to create the modern system of disciplinary power.
See Foucault: (http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/foucault/).
[11] The use of words such ‘assault’ and ‘invasion’ have been a rhetoric repeatedly used by far-right Italian political parties such as the Lega del Nord (Northern League) (view footnote 12), to emphasise and stress, with sinister undertones, that migrants arriving in Sicily is the equivalent to and invasion/assault on Italy;
“Da sempre la Lega è contro l’invasione dei clandestini che scardinano l’identità della nostra società: le identità culturali e quella religiosa, quella cattolica. Siamo contrari all’intera catena di montaggio che prima attira e facilita l’ingresso dei clandestini e poi attraverso le sanatorie li regolarizza”.
Transalation: “The Northern League has always been against the invasion of clandestines, who destroy our national identity: our cultural and religious identity, the catholic one. We are against the whole system that first attracts and facilitates the entry of clandestines” (Lega del Nord, 2000:40).
[12] Translation “a reduction of immigrants means a reduction of criminals”.
[13] Translation: “My task is to promote a vigorous line in terms of security…The principle is to guarantee maximum security for the citizens and the prevent as well as fight in a rigorous manner clandestine immigration and to assert the principle of legality”
[14] The interaction between politics, migration and the media is a well-researched phenomenon of Italy, see: Sciortino, G. & Colombo, A., (2004), Gli Immigrati in Italia, Bologna: Il Mulino
[15] Under the UNHCR 1951 convention, of which Italy is a signatory, any person with a “well-founded fear of being persecuted for reasons of race, religion, nationality, membership of a particular social group or political opinion” is allowed to claim asylum protection under “the so-called principle of non-refoulement, i.e. that no Contracting State shall expel or return (“refouler”) a refugee, against his or her will…to a territory where he or she fears persecution” (UNHCR,2007:16,5). In so, Italy in implementing ‘repatriation flights’ has been criticised of subordinating the 1951 convention.
[16] See:
-O.A.U, (10th September 1969), Convention Governing the Specific Aspects of Refugee Problems in Africa. Refugee Convention.
-http://www.icrc.org/Web/Eng/siteeng0.nsf/html/genevaconventions.
[17] Case-studies producing evidence of forms of forced Labour: (Del Grande, 2007:22)
1) Kamal, Morocco
“We had suffered a shipwreck off the Libyan coast. They rescued and then took us to prison in al Fellah, in Tripoli. Every day, they brought us to do some forced labour. If you told the police officers that you didn’t know how to do a job, they would beat you. And if you complained that you were tired, the same would happen. They didn’t care if the only thing we got to eat was a fistful of rice and a baguette”.
2) Ayman, Tunisia
“Every day, from al Fellah, a team of around twenty people left to do forced labour in the mountain, in the fields”.
[18] Case-studies evidencing migrants being deported and abandon in desert: (Del Grande, 2007:25)
1) Fabrice, Togo
“From Qatrun, they loaded us into a lorry and abandoned us on the border with Niger, at the height of Toumou. We had to walk for three days, under the sun, to reach Madama, in Niger”.
2) Elvis, Cameroon
“They deported us all, from Qatrun to Toumou, on the border with Niger. Toumou is an oasis where Libyan border soldiers live. They had abandoned us there, under the sun, two days’ walk away from Qatrun, and just as many from Madama, across the border in Niger. We used the glare of the lights of the oasis at night to find our way. In September 2007, there were 150 migrants living in Toumou who are completely blocked, without any money to continue the journey, some of whom have gone mad. The smugglers who were returning from Libya gave us a lift towards Dirkou. But then they unloaded us two days’ walk away from Dirkou. And once we finally arrived in Dirkou, the Niger policemen refused to receive us. They recovered the corpses of two travel companions of ours who had died under the sun, and then loaded us onto an off-road vehicle to take us back to Toumou. The Libyan police took us 25 back to Qatrun. Two weeks later, a Nigerian friend who I met in prison again bribed a guard and they freed us once more”.
3) Yakob, Ethiopia
“They leave for the desert and, half-way there, they ask you for money to go back. I met a youth in Zuwarah who had spent six months in Kufrah and was then deported. They were fifty in the lorry. Half-way there, the driver asked them to pay three hundred dollars each. Only thirty of them had the money. They went back with them. The other twenty were ditched in the desert. They will have died under the sun, surely. They even take money that you don’t have from you. If, for example, you don’t have any money on you, but you have a relative in Europe who is able to pay, before abandoning you on the border, they lend you their satellite mobile phone to call and ask them for a Western Union money order”.
[19] A further issue regarding, is that when repatriated, human trafficking victims are, with growing evidence filtered back into trafficking rings, such as the case in Eastern Europe documented by Demir (2003), (Demir,2003:12).
[20] Guardia di Finanza is a special force affiliated to the Police force and dependent on the Ministry of Economy and Finance. It is organised and integrated by the Armed Forces (Forze Armate dello Stato) and the Public Forces (Forze Pubblica) (http://www.gdf.it/Organizzazione/Chi_siamo/I_Compiti_del_Corpo/index.html). -
[21] “Libya is one of the countries that have been severely affected by migration. It has depleted our resources. We have twice or three times as many people as our own in Libya. We feed them, house them, provide them with transportation, and they take their share of all the cheap products subsidized by the Libyan budget” –Al Qaddafi, 2006 (Paoletti,2009:6)
[22] “Criminalisation of migrants has been further strengthened at a European level since the start of the 2000s, in the context of the «war against terrorism» after the attacks of 11 September 2001” (Molessi, 2008)